Tuesday, April 10, 2007

Summary of chapter 4: Government Money with Portfolio Choice

Model PC (portfolio choice) is a continuation on the Model SIM. Agents must choose between money and financial assets. Their decision is aided through the rate of interest on other assets; hence it is called Porfolio choice.

The Matrices of Model PC

Government bills, interest payment and a central bank are all added to Model SIM to make up Model PC. In the balance sheet of Model PC, the first column is for Households, which contain money H or bills Bh, the sum of these 2 is private wealth (V). There is no production sector as it is assumed to be a pure service economy, which means the value of the household sector is also the value of the private sector. Column 3 consists of public debt – amount of outstanding bills B issued by the Government to households and the central bank together. In column 4 includes the central bank purchasing bills from government, which increases its stock of assets Bch. On the other side the central bank provides money to households.

The two differences from the Model SIM flow matrix are that flow-of-funds accounts include two financial assets and there are interest payments on government debt. National income doesn’t include these interest payments; it consists of income derived from the sales to households and to the government. The new central bank sector consists of a current account (involves the inflows and outflows of daily activities) and the capital account (shows changes in the balance sheet). It is assumed that the central bank has zero net worth and profits are always paid to the government.

The equations of the Model PC

The first model assumes that producers sell exactly what is demanded and that households have correct expectations regarding their incomes. It begins with production is equal to consumption plus government expenditure. Godley follows by defining disposable income (4.2) and taxable income (4.3). Both (4.2) and (4.3) are includes interest payments.

  • Y = C + G (4.1)
  • YD = Y – T + r-1. Bh-1 (4.2)
  • T = Ơ . (Y + r-1 . Bh-1) (4.3)

Keynes two-stage decision means households decide how much they will save and how they will allocate their wealth between money and bills. V is total wealth.

  • V = V-1 + (YD – C) (4.4)

Consumption now includes total wealth;

  • C = α1 . YD + α2 . V-1 0< α2< α1<1 (4.5)
    Wealth is allocated between bonds and money dependent on the interest rates and liquidity preferences. However the allocation will always sum to one to satisfy the following formulas;
  • Hh/V = (1- λ0) – λ1 . r + λ2 . YD/V (4.6A)
  • Bh/V = λ0 + λ1 . r - λ2. YD/V (4.7)

To solve the model, with the demand for cash a residual equation (4.6A) is dropped and (4.6) is used.

  • Hh = V – Bh (4.6)

Money holdings is the total wealth and the demand for bills by households.

Equations (4.8)-(4.11) involve the government and central bank.

  • ∆Bs = Bs – Bs-1 = (G + r-1 . Bs-1) – (T + r-1 . BCB-1) (4.8)
  • ∆Hs = Hs – Hs-1 = ∆Bcb (4.9)
  • Bcb = Bs - Bh (4.10)
  • R = r (4.11)

Equation (4.8) explains the government budget constraint. Equation (4.9) shows the capital account of the central bank. Equation (4.10) and (4.11) are related to the fact that the central bank purchase all governmental bills that households don’t want. The interest rate will affect this amount.
Given these equations, the cash household’s have is equal to the cash provided by the central bank.

  • Hh = Hs (4.12)

Expectations in Model PC

Consumption will depend on expected income and that expectation is usually incorrect. Therefore the Consumption function is now;

  • C = α1 . YDe + α2 . V-1 (4.5E)

YDe is the expected disposable income. The rest of the equations must be changed because wealth as well as income is unknown.

Any miscalculation of expected disposable income is balanced by a change in money balances. This means, households actually invest in bills on the basis of their expectations with respect to disposable income from the beginning of the period.

  • Therefore Bh = Bd (4.15)

Expected disposable income including the possibility of a random process is defined as;

  • YDe = YD . (1 + Ra) (4.16)

Our conclusion from earlier equations is that the difference in the amount of money held and demanded by households is dependent on expected income, which is equal to the difference between realised and expected income.

  • Hh – Hd = YD -YDe (4.17)

The Steady State

The effect of rising interest rates on the allocation of wealth between cash and bills is examined, assuming no change in external variables and opening from a full stationary state.

A higher interest rate means that households would hold more interest paying bills as would be expected due to the rate of return being higher at a constant level of risk.

Although it is also found that a higher interest rate encourages an increase in disposable income and consumption both in the short run and in the new stationary state.To explain this unusual result, the steady state solution for national income is established. The government budget must be balanced (government revenue plus central bank profits equal to government expenditures plus cost of servicing government debt)

The steady-state solution for national income is determined:

  • Y* = G + r.Bh*.(1 - θ)/θ (4.18)

The steady state solutions for disposable income can also be obtained keeping in mind that in the stationary state consumption equals disposable income:

  • C* = YD* = Y* + r.Bh* - T* = Y* + r.Bh* - θ.(Y* + r.Bh*) (4.18)


It can be seen that in the full stationary state the aggregate income flow and disposable income flow are an increasing function of the interest rate. As higher interest payments accumulate on government debt, disposable income increases as does consumption and national income. . As disposable income increases households hold more wealth and a larger absolute amount of bills as well as a larger proportion of their wealth in bills. All of this leads to even larger interest payments on debt. Higher interest rates generate more economic activity.


Fully developed solutions

The solutions need to be examined further because the value of Bh* needs to be found in terms of the different limits and need to put this value into the equations to reach the fully developed stationary solutions of the Model PC.

To do this the wealth accumulation function is obtained

  • ∆V = α2 . (α3 . YD – V – 1) (4.20)

Noting that in the stationary steady state households accumulate no additional wealth and so ∆V equals zero. Thus wealth and disposable income are in a constant ratio, combining this ratio with the portfolio decisions of households eventually highlights that the steady state level of GDP is dependant on the fiscal stance which, whatever the target wealth to disposable income ratio and the average interest rate payable on overall government liabilities depends on the G/ θ ratio.

  • Y* = (G/ θ ) { 1 + α3. (1 – θ) . ѓ (4.26)
    [θ/(1- θ)] - α3 . ѓ }

Implications of changes in parameter values for temporary and steady state income

Puzzling results

An increase in the permanent level of government expenditure boosts the stationary level of income and disposable income; dY*/dG >0.

Any permanent decrease in the on the whole tax rate θ has the same effect; dY*/d θ <0.

Alternatively an increase in the interest rate or in the rate of interest payable on government liabilities leads to an increase in the steady state level of income and disposable income as the higher rate increases payments arising from the government sector thus leading to more consumers spending from households. Also the higher rate of return on bills means households will hold more interest paying government debt.

An increase in the desire to hold bills increases the proportion of government debt taking the form of bills, thus raising ѓ leading to an increase in the steady state value of national income. So holding more bills leads to an increase in national income.

The model also shows that any increase the wealth to disposable income ratio (a3), leads to an increase in stationary income or disposable income. This is because dY*/a3 >0 where a3 = (1-a1)/ a2. (Where a1 and a2 are the propensities to consume out of current income and out of accumulated wealth.) Thus if households decide to save larger amounts of both their income and wealth then the level of steady state income will be higher.

This result challenges a ‘paradox of thrift’ that has been stated by Keynes. If people decide to save more at each level of income one might expect that this would increase the total amount of savings, but Keynesian multiplier model predicts a paradox of thrift, that total savings will remain the same and income will decline. The reason that higher thrift leads to higher stationary level of income is because a larger a3 parameter suggests households aim for a higher wealth level, but a higher wealth objective implies higher interest payments on government debt held by households and in due course higher absolute consumption and income levels once the steady state is reached.


Graphical Analysis

Assuming that:

  • Expectations about current disposable income are based on actual disposable income in the previous period and
  • An increase in the propensity to consume implied a decrease in the target wealth to disposable income ratio


An increase in the propensity to consume out of disposable income causes GDP to rise in the short run, but in the long run a lower steady state value is achieved which is lower than the original steady state National Income operates as follows.

National income first rises in the short run because for a given level of accumulated wealth when households increase consumption out of current income there is an increase in aggregate demand leading to an increase in national income. However, the propensity to save decreases, reducing the stock of wealth as consumption exceeds disposable income. Ultimately the reduced consumption out of the wealth compensates for higher consumption out of current income. Wealth and consumption keep falling and national income falls to reach steady state level which is lower than the initial steady state.


Why then with a higher propensity to consume does both household wealth and government debt fall? This is due to fact the starting point is a stationary state which indicates the private sector is neither saving /dissaving and the government budget is balanced. As household consume more, their wealth is falling. There is increased revenue for government which means the budget is in surplus and the debt level can be reduced. So both household wealth and government debt decrease by the same amount.

The consequences of an increase in the rate of interest set by the central bank is also shown assuming we begin from a stationary position where accumulated wealth is the targeted level of wealth. Any increase in the rate of interest or the propensity to consume leads to a brief increase in disposable and national incomes. The target level of wealth also increases, suggesting that households will be increasing savings and their demand for bills. In the next period, consumption and income rise, leading to a higher stationary level of income.

The effect of a decrease in the propensity to consume out of current income is examined. The target wealth to income ratio would rise as a result. There would be an initial fall in national income but there would also be a difference between current wealth and target levels of wealth, making it appealing for households to buy bills.


The puzzling impact of interest rates reconsidered

Assuming the propensity to save is not constant, but is a value which depends negatively on the interest rate on bills.

The first result of the increased interest rate is that it causes a fall in consumption, disposable income and national income.

However this model takes stocks into account. A reduction in the propensity to consume increases the target wealth to income ratio, leading to an increase in the stock of wealth. If households’ wealth keeps increasing consumption demand is lower than disposable income once household wealth is increasing.

There is also an increase in government debt. The short term recession caused by the higher interest rates on consumption drives tax revenues down. This negative effect is heightened by an increase in government expenditures due to higher cost of debt. This causes a budget deficit. This deficit gets smaller as government expenditures and taxes continue to increase up to stationary level where the government budget is balanced, and eventually the deficit flow is wiped out by rising consumption expenditures encouraged by increasing household wealth.


A Government target for the debt to income ratio


Godley asks can the government do anything about the debt to income ratio in the long run.

In this model the ratio is defined as V/ Y where V is the wealth of households which corresponds to government debt and Y is national income or GDP This ratio is determined by the behaviour of households.

If households are trying to achieve a high wealth ratio government could attempt to achieve a budget surplus (e.g. by reducing expenditure) but this would be unsuccessful as there would be a reduction in disposable income, but no change in the ratio unless the reduction in income led to households revising their saving propensities.

Government and securities rating agencies are more concerned with public debt as a ratio of GDP, which is easier to adjust. If households are targeting too high a wealth ratio, the government can reduce its stationary debt to GDP ratio. If government wishes to decrease this, they need to increase tax rates or reduce interest rate on bills, resulting in a reduced level of stationary income. Thus, the debt to income ratio must be disregarded to sustain full employment income. This is irreconcilable with maintaining full employment in the long run.

Sunday, April 1, 2007

Table 3.4 of Godley/Lavoie

(1) Complete values for table if tax rate is 20%
(2) Complete values for table if tax rate is 30%

(3) Complete values for table in period 2 if tax rate is 30%


(1)

Y = G/(1-a1+a1θ) 38.5

T = θ *Y = 38.5*0.2 7.7
YD = Y - T = 38.5 - 7.7 30.8
C = a1*YD + a2*H-1 = 0.6*30.8 + 0.4*0 18.5
∆Hs = G - T = 20 - 7.7 12.3
∆Hh = YD - C = 30.8 - 18.5 12.3

H =∆Hh + H-1 = 12.3 + 0 12.3

(2)

Y = 34.48

T = 0.3*34.48 10.34
YD = 34.48 - 10.34 24.14
C = 0.6*24.14 + 0.4*0 14.48
∆Hs = 20 - 10.34 9.66
∆Hh = 24.14 - 14.5 9.66
H = 9.64 + 0 9.66


(3)

Y = 34.48 + a2*H-1 34.48 + 0.4*9.65 = 38.36
T = 0.3*38.36 = 11.5
YD = 38.36 - 11.5 = 26.86
C = 0.6*26.86 + 0.4*9.65 = 16.11 + 3.86 = 19.98
ChangeHs = 20 - 11.5 = 8.5
ChangeHh = 26.86 – 19.98 = 6.88
H = 6.88+ 9.65 = 16.53



Monday, March 19, 2007

3.1:
Outside money means the government makes a draft and banknotes for its payments. Inside money (private money) is made by commercial banks or private institutions. Both these ways of money creation and destruction is important to study the complete monetary economy in the real world. However, a hypothetical economy is assumed in which there is a world without any private money, banks, borrowing and interest. This assumption explains why the private bank loan is an important item in the real economic world. It is essential to understand the stock-flow macro-economics rules.

3.2:

A simple model SIM is the starting point for this analysis and built from there. SIM assumes:
A closed economy- No imports/exports
All production undertaken by service providers - no capital equipment and no intermediate costs of production.
Services are instantly provided so unlike manufacturing no inventories exist.
No private banks - government buys services and pays them with the money it printsThe economy is demand-led, i.e. unlimited labour force etc as production responds to demand.

SIM introduces a behavioural matrix explaining each sectors stock of assets and liabilities and how each sector relates to another such that all columns and rows in this matrix sum to zero. It’s players are: households, producers and the government and the transactions are: consumption, government expenditure, output, wages, taxes and change in money stock -Hh +Hh. The balance sheet has money (H) which is an asset to households and a liability to government. Producers are assumed not to hold cash. . The wage bill is the only source of income for household; can be used to pay tax, buy services or buy financial assets. A crucial element of the matrix is total production which is an exception as it is not a transaction between sectors. It is equal to the sum of all spent on goods/services.

3.3
The accounting matrices cannot show how the system works. Therefore, we need to introduce behavioral transactions matrix in order to understand the system as a whole. In the matrix, the vertical columns must sum to zero because the change in the amount of money held must be the same as the households’ income minus their payments. It is similar for government.
There are several mechanisms to insure the supply and demand in the behavioral matrix equal.
1. Neoclassical theory
Higher prices caused by excess demand reduce the excess demand.
2. Rationing theory
Imposing rigid price, this theory believe that the adjustment is done on the short side of the market when supply and demand are not equal.
3. Inventories theory
The theory indicates that there are always enough inventories to absorb the difference between supply and demand.
4. Keynesian quantity adjustment mechanism
Keynesian mechanism base on the premise that production is the flexible element and there are no inventories. The equality between demand and supply is achieved by the quantity adjustment.
Equations of model SIM:
1. YD = W • Ns – Ts
Disposable income equal to wages of households less taxes paid.
2. Td = θ · W · Ns θ< 1
Taxes are deduced from income on the tax rate.
3. Cd = a1 · YD + a2 · Hh-1 0 < a2 < a1 <1
Consumption equals to some proportion of disposable income and some smaller proportion of reserved income.
4. ΔHs = Hs – Hs-1 = Gd – Td
The change in the stock of money of government is the same as the difference between government receipts and outlays in the same period.
5. ΔHn = Hh- Hh-1 = YD – Cd
The accumulated wealth of households equals to disposable income less expenditure.
The following equations illustrate the determination of output and empolyment
6. Y = Cs + Gs
6. Y = W · Nd
7. Nd = Y / W
8. ΔHh = ΔHs
Thus, including the 4 basic equations the SIM model has 11 equations and 11 unknown parameters.

3.4
A numerical example and the standard Keynesian multiplier
This chapter focuses on “the standard Keynesian multiplier”, and the numerical example shows how this model evolves through time, starting with the beginning of the world. This chapter considers whether the multiplier should be interpreted as a logical relationship, occurring within the period, as has been done here, or as a dynamic relationship, occurring over several periods, possibly using trial and error. On the other hand, the drawbacks are also mentioned. First, the view of the multiplier process lacks coherence. Second, the model SIM deals with flows, while not take into account the impact of flows on stocks and the subsequent impact of stocks on flows.


3.5

The model assumes a steady state which means that both flows and stocks change at the same rate and are in a constant relationship to each other .As we omit growth we assume a stationary steady state in which government expenditure equals tax receipts so that no surplus/deficit exists and hence a zero change in the stock of money. It also assumes that consumption must be the same as disposable income and the stock of past accumulated wealth.

3. 6
Another interpretation of the consumption function is offered in terms of a wealth accumulation function

Consumption is disposable income minus the household savings of the period. Households have a defined level of wealth they want. If the target level is below the actual level households will save in order to achieve their target thus consumption will always be below disposable income until the target is reached. Once the target has been passed no more saving will occur and the stationary state is reached.
3.7

The government expenditure is equal to tax receipts in both these two sections. The relationship between income and government expenditure can be descried as
Y*=G/θ
The G/θ ratio means when the income increases and the government expenditure is steady, then the average tax rate will be reduced. This result can be called fiscal stance.
There is two fundamental property of the steady-state such as
(1) As the average tax rate is constant, the aggregate income will increases at the same level when the government expenditure increases.
(2) In a stationary state, there is no savings because of there is no change in financial stocks. So, YD*=C*= G· (1-θ) /θ
This equation expresses the relationship between the disposable income and government expenditure that is the disposable income can be increased as the government increases its expenditure.
Also the equation shows us there is an equal relationship between the consumption with disposable income in the stationary state.

3.8
Stability analysis is important in the dynamic module and coefficient can be used to measure it. In form of equation H = A + BH -1, the B coefficient next to H-1 is always positive. This means the module towards stationary when it is out-of- equilibrium. Therefore, the change of money balances according to time increases in step until it


3.9

The author uses a graphical to illustrate the model of SIM. Especially, the author tries to use two kinds of way to answer the question which are “given the various household consumption parameters and fiscal policy parameters set by government, what is the level of production compatible with aggregate demand?” The short-run answer used different periods of cash money balances to calculate. On the other hand, the long-run answer thought the level of wealth is an endogenous variable.

Sunday, March 18, 2007

Excel Spreadsheet Q in class

An the excel spreadsheet was given , in which a level of income was given, and from this income some is saved . This is the withdrawal row. In a closed economy, injections always equal withdrawals. There also was a randomly allocated investment. It was required that we balanced the system, so we set the withdrawal level to make the level of income equal to the level of aggregate expenditure, which is just a sum of the other rows. To do this we had to work out the marginal propensity to consume, this is calculated by dividing the change in consumption by the change in income and if it was say, 0.8, then you'd set 30% of your income towards withdrawals to get the system close to equilibrium. Aggregate expenditure is the sum of income, consumption and injections, less withdrawals. To balance the system, one adjusts the withdrawals figure until income equals aggregate expenditure.

Q2

Q.2 Write out an explanation for each row.

Consumption – Consumers buy products with their income (-Cd) . Producers produce what is demanded and are paid (+Cs) for this.

Government Expenditure – The government buys goods/services (-Gd). Producers get the money in return for producing what is demanded (+Gd).

Output – This is all money spent on goods/services and is seen to be the total production of an economy.

Factor Income – Producers need a labour force to produce goods/services. This costs
(-W.Ns).The labour is provided by households who earn (+W.Ns).


Taxes – Households are charged taxes by the government (-Td) while the government receives this in order redistribute it for the public benefit.(+Td).

Change in money stock – Households will not always immediately spend but will save money which they may use to buy financial assets (- change Hh). . By the Government providing these financial assets they receive additional income to what to get in taxes. (+ change Hs)

Consumption Function

Definition:

Keynes devised this function to state consumer spending as one term. It is shown as a linear function and explains how consumption expenditure depends on the level of income. The consumption function shows that what people spend depends on their income, and that as income increases, so does consumption.

C = a + mpc * Y


Where
c = total consumption

a = autonomous consumption i.e. consumption when income is zero so therefore it is consumption which is not influenced by current income.

mpc = the marginal propensity to consume i.e. the rate at which consumption is changing when income changes.

Y=disposable income

Note also that mpc * Y is induced consumption , i.e. consumption influenced by the economy’s income level.

The concept revolves around the fact that a consumer’s expenditure depends on his or her disposable income. Real income is money income adjusted for inflation. It is a measure of the quantity of goods and services that consumers have buy with their income.
·There is normally a positive relationship between disposable income and consumer spending. This fraction of additional income that people spend is called the marginal propensity to consume. MPC = (change in consumption) divided by (change in income)The gradient of the consumption curve gives the marginal propensity to consume. As income rises, so does total consumer demand.
· A change in the marginal propensity to consume causes a pivotal change in the consumption function. In this case the marginal propensity to consume has fallen leading to a fall in consumption at each level of income.

The Keynesian consumption function is based on current income only and does not consider future income . Therefore extensions of this theory are Friedman's permanent income hypothesis and Modigliani's life cycle hypothesis.

Example:
An increase of disposable income could result in higher level of consumer expenditure. Also, the level of consumption depends on the change in MPC. As the MPC goes up, the consumption will increase.

References:
www.businessdictionary.com
www.tutor2u.net/economics/content
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Consumption_function
http://www.ingrimayne.com/econ/Keynes/SimpleModel.html